Improving the NCAA’s guideline of Payments to athletes

By Stephen A. Miller[1]

For decades, the national Collegiate Athletics association (NCAA) resisted efforts to allow its athletes to earn outside income.  The association delayed, litigated, formed some task forces, delayed some more… but eventually surrendered in July 2021 after its appeal to the U.S. supreme Court on this issue was unanimously rejected.  The surrender carried an crucial caveat, though, and one that will become even a lot more relevant as the NCAA meets in the coming months to reconsider its policies and governance model.

The NCAA’s announcement, on June 30th, suspended nearly all of the Association’s restrictions on so-called Name, image and Likeness (NIL) income earned by its athletes.  Some restrictions remained in effect.  Specifically, the NCAA emphasized that it was preserving “the commitment to avoid pay-for-play and improper inducements tied to choosing to attend a particular school.  Those policies remain in effect.” <> 

But even those restrictions are unworkable, if interpreted rigidly.  and given the NCAA’s comical record on discipline, those broad policies can never be meaningfully enforced.  The NCAA needs to be realistic.  Its all-or-nothing technique on amateurism policies is what sowed the seeds of the current revolution.

For its own survival, the association needs to do better.  next week, the NCAA’s Board of Governors will receive recommendations for new policies and structures for regulating college sports.  Its focus must be on preserving only those restrictions on amateurism that are needed for fair, competitive play on the field.  Some aspects of the pay-for-play prohibitions must remain, for example, but only where they incentivize performance that diverges from the team’s competitive goals.  and the limits on inducements are so easily evaded, and the contours so amorphous, that the NCAA will not be able to enforce them in a principled way.  Instead, the association must regulate only the most egregious inducements that manipulate athletes and their trusted relationships.  By trying to sweep a lot more broadly, the NCAA invites failure that will additionally erode its credibility and, ultimately, its members’ view of its necessity.

*          *          *

The term “pay-for-play” evokes images of back-room dealing and political corruption.  In NCAA parlance, it refers to compensation tied to participation or achievement in a sporting contest.  If athletes earned money for their exploits on the field of play, how could the NCAA proclaim them to be “amateurs” who played only for the love of the sport?

The illusion of pure “amateurism” has always been just that: an illusion.  The NCAA tried hard to promote this image, but the billions of dollars in media contracts, coaches’ salaries, and opulent facilities became too dissonant to ignore.  The players were the only ones who weren’t sharing in the wealth.

The new world of NIL payments has begun to change that.  Is there a still a place for restrictions on “pay-for-play,” performance-based compensation?  The answer is yes, in limited circumstances.  When the NCAA adopts new NIL rules, it must prohibit conduct that would incentivize performance in an athletic contest that would impair the players’ loyalty to her team or otherwise negatively affect the decision-making and competition on the field.

Payments should, however, be allowed if they promote behavior consistent with the team’s competitive interests.  For example, if a local restaurant used complimentary dinner to all players of a team for each victory, this would only incentivize conduct in service of the team’s goals.

A few examples illustrate why incentive payments based on individual statistics in team sports are problematic.  They must not be per se invalid, but they would require a closer look to make sure that they promote the team’s interests.  The inquiry would be similar to that in lots of states’ commercial-bribery laws — does the payment cause the player to be devoted to interests other than those of his team?  A few hypothetical examples make the point:

A local grocery uses $100 for every home run by a college baseball player. In theory, home runs would seem to help the team… but this incentive might cause the player to “swing for the fences” in a way that leads him to strike out more, or — worse — disregard his coach’s instructions to bunt or hit to the opposite field.

A national bank agrees to pay a star basketball player $500 for every attempted “bank” shot (off the backboard). This causes the player not only to shoot more, but also to goal consistently for the backboard, regardless of distance or angle from the hoop, instead of finishing shots in the most effective manner allowed in each moment.  Unless the player is an elite trick-shot artist, she would likely be hurting her team by exhibiting a lot more loyalty to her financial interests than taking the highest-percentage shot (or pass) for her team’s success.

A seafood restaurant agrees to pay $1000 to each college swimmer that achieves a new personal-record time in an NCAA meet. This payment perfectly aligns the interests of the athlete and the team, and it must be permissible.

Administering this conventional would admittedly be art, not science.  It would likely only work if the NCAA required pre-clearance of proposed NIL contracts in this category — and only then if the NCAA actually committed sufficient resources to review proposed deals quickly.  The administrative problem would be negligible, and kicking back this policy would open up a lot more and creative avenues for athletes to earn income.  Some is better than none, and this might be a workable exception to an outright ban on all pay-for-play compensation.

*          *          *

The NCAA must do a similar surgery to save only the vital portion of its ban on “improper inducements tied to choosing to attend a particular school.”  As an initial matter, it is worth noting that the word “improper” is forced to do too much work here.  Does it indicate “morally improper?”  likely not, and by whose moral conventional anyway?  The definition of “improper,” in reality, is circular and question-begging — improper indicates whatever the NCAA says it indicates through other, a lot more certain rules.

It seems fair to allow the NCAA to restrict inducement payments to an athlete’s parents or coaches or “handlers” — i.e., payments to someone other than the athlete herself.  Those payments reduce the athlete’s autonomy by influencing her Camiseta Newcastle United college choice by manipulating long-time, trusted relationships through payments typically unknown to the athlete.  Moreover, they deprive the athlete of compensation earned by her efforts.  A major motivation of allowing NIL payments, in the first place, is to share with athletes a piece of the financial pie generated by their efforts; payments to any individual other than the athletes do not accomplish that goal and, thus, they must be regulated.

But payments directly to an athlete to induce his choice of school?  Those are a a lot more tough call.  Morally, the athlete has full agency over his decision and can weigh the relevant aspects for himself (even if others might quibble with the weight afforded to monetary factors).  Legally, restrictions on this income run the risk of triggering the antitrust worries raised by Justice Kavanaugh in his scolding concurrence in the recent Alston case.  Nonetheless, critics are ideal to note the competitive advantage of bigger schools over smaller schools in this system, but that is an inherent feature of a complimentary market; the supreme Court has previewed that it will take a dim view of the NCAA’s attempts to regulate the complimentary market in this area.

Any decision on this issue need to also confront the substantial costs to enforce such a restriction.  colleges will rightly complain that they and their athletes can be punished for NIL contracts without their knowledge by unaffiliated services trying to get a connection to their favorite (or rival!) team.  how are colleges to police this activity?  hire full-time staffs of forensic accountants and private investigators?  a lot more fundamentally, can we expect colleges or the NCAA to translate the nuances of NIL negotiations, and conclude with confidence that one offer represented a pledge to pay money whereas the other just represented a statement of probable interest?  Is there a meaningful difference between those two when regulating “inducements?”

Those questions are rhetorical, of course.  The NCAA’s woeful record of enforcing prior violations of the Association’s policies suggests that an explosion of alleged “NIL inducement” cases would never be investigated — much less adjudicated — with any alacrity or rigor.  If the NCAA is unwilling to enforce a restriction, and the restriction can be evaded easily, there is little compelling justification to preserve the restriction.

Regardless of the strong arguments on each side of that issue, there is a strong argument that team-wide NIL payments must be permitted under the new NCAA rules.  several NCAA football and men’s basketball teams have already signed these deals, which pledge equivalent benefits to each member of the team:

University of Tennessee (football) — an apparel company agreed to direct proceeds from the sale of a particular tee shirt to all football players.

University of Mississippi (football) — a blue jeans company based in Tupelo used each football player a complimentary pair of customized jeans ($450 value) in exchange for promoting the company through social media.

Florida state university (football) and Miami university (basketball) — Yummy Crypto (a start-up cryptocurrency company) used $500/month to all eligible Florida state football and Miami basketball players in exchange for weekly social-media articles promoting the company.

Miami university (football) — American top Team, an MMA training academy, used contracts to every Miami scholarship football player ($500 each month, up to $6,000 per year) to endorse the academy through social media accounts, personal appearances, and other marketing efforts.

BYU — built Bar, a nutrition supplement, signed a multi-year deal for entire football team (scholarship and walk-on players alike); the deal includes compensation sufficient to supply full-tuition scholarships for every walk-on player on the 123-man roster, which is somewhere around $6,000 for Utah residents. Under this deal, every player will wear built branding on their practice helmets, participate in company-sponsored events, and some will be asked to promote the product Camiseta Racing Club de Avellaneda on social media.

There is nothing in these deals to suggest that they will evaporate when future athletes join these teams.  Is the probability (or certainty) of that future NIL income an “improper inducement” to the NCAA?  If the NCAA thinks so, it will be endorsing the same rigidity and magical thinking about its own enforcement abilities that brought the association to this point.  It must instead execute a calculated surrender for at least this category of NIL payment.

The equal-payment structure promotes team unity and does not create an economic hierarchy within the locker room.  Moreover, when a service pays a large number of athletes, the amounts of the individual payments are nearly certainly a lot more modest than if it used that same money to pay only a few individual payments.  Those modest amounts, by their nature, are less likely to serve as “improper inducements” that implicate the policy worries of individualized, direct payments, even if a recruit understands that she is likely to inherit those payments when she joins the team in the future.  These team-wide payments also seem to vindicate the economic-fairness principles driving the entire NIL dispute — i.e., redistributing some of the income and sponsorship dollars to the players themselves.

*          *          *

The NCAA will begin to consider a working draft of a revised constitution next week.  The full NCAA membership will vote on a new set of governing principles in January 2022.  policies governing NIL payments will certainly be a part of this new constitution; there is no going back to the old model of “amateurism.”  When prioritizing which NIL payments to regulate, the NCAA must not object to payments that incentivize behavior consistent with the team’s competitive interests.  The association must also narrowly define “improper” inducements as those that divert money away from the athlete herself and that specifically exempt team-wide payments.

[1]              Stephen A. Miller is a criminal-defense attorney at Cozen O’Connor in Philadelphia, where his practice includes the representation of student-athletes in eligibility disputes with the NCAA.  prior to joining Cozen O’Connor, he clerked for Justice Antonin Scalia on the U.S. supreme Court Camiseta AS Roma and served as a federal prosecutor for nine years in both the southern district of new York and the Eastern district of Pennsylvania.

Share this:
Facebook
Twitter
Email

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published.